Pundit

View Original

The End of Neoliberalism?

Gary Gerstle’s The Rise and Fall of the Neoliberal Order: America and the World in the Free Market Era is a frustrating book. It is an impressive sweeping history of American politics and economic policy from the New Deal in the 1930s to today, predicting that we are coming to the end of the ‘neoliberal’ era. However, Gerstle never defines what he means by ‘neoliberal’ other than with examples through the narrative, so it is difficult to be able to identify what is coming to an end and when.

A Professor of History at the University of Cambridge, Gerstle’s central notion is ‘political orders’, in which ways of thinking and policy frameworks dominate what is done and how it is talked about. (Sonia Mazey and Jeremy Richardson of the University of Canterbury talk about ‘policy styles’, which is much the same thing. Their recently published Policy-making Under Pressure: Rethinking the Policy Process in Aotearoa New Zealand applies their approach locally.)

Gerstle argues, reasonably convincingly, that there have been two broad political orders in the US in the last ninety years. New Zealand parallels the pattern, which is why we need to think about whether the second one is coming to an end. The ‘New Deal’ first was triggered by the election of Roosevelt in 1932. New Zealand’s trigger was the first Labour Government, although there are precursors in Coates’ initiatives in the preceding Coalition Government. The ‘neoliberalism’ second began with Reagan in 1980, with the New Zealand equivalent precipitated by Roger Douglas during the Third Labour Government.

The difficulty with this narrative is that both paradigms evolved, as Gerstle describes but does not reflect upon. He says Obama pursued neoliberal policies, but surely he does not include Obamacare. Again, one could accuse the Ardern-Robertson Labour Government of being neoliberal, but this ignores that there has been a considerable retreat from the policies introduced by Douglas and Richardson throughout the thirty-odd years since. (Many would argue the retreat has been insufficient; the point is that there has been one.)

What I find uncomfortable about the Gerstle approach is that whatever the historian’s narrative power – he certainly writes well – it lacks analytic power. It is easy enough to say neoliberalism rose, but why then? And that it is failing, but why now? Trying to answer these questions shifts one from history to political economy – to use the phrase in its nineteenth century meaning.

You can get a sense of the difference from my Not in Narrow Seas. Certainly it has a historical narrative but I tried to explain what were the underlying drivers of the political economy and hence the political order/style. For instance, I do not see ‘neoliberalism’ in New Zealand simply as a consequence of the arrival of ideologists who seized power.

Rather, the old policy paradigm was breaking down in the face of increased affluence, diversity, urbanisation, and opportunities from globalisation plus a host of new technological innovations. The centralised control of the economy was too clumsy and inflexible.

This does not mean the neoliberalism revolution was inevitable. (It did not happeen to the same extent on the European Continent). However a handful of extremists grabbed power and imposed it, while repressing dissent. That is why there has been a steady roll back of the more excessive changes. But Gerstle would argue that New Zealand was still in a neoliberal political order. Is it a dying order?

The analytics says that something has to change for the death. A Marxist could argue that it is collapsing under its contradictions and excesses. But any order which has survived four decades requires a little more than inherent contradictions to collapse. In any case, the approach does not tell us what will replace it.

However there are changes which are undermining neoliberalism. But, hey Brian, you are as bad as Gerstle, you haven’t defined what you mean by ‘neoliberalism’. My neoliberalism is not everything I disagree with, which is often the way Gerstle presents his case. Rather, I define it as an approach which minimises the role of the state in the economy.

(I found Gerstle’s discussion on the neoliberal approach to social relations especially valuable. He details how they generally support a neo-Victorian moral code, including a punitive criminal regime. Trump, of course, has not such a code; Pence is at the other end of the spectrum. The US Supreme Court has shifted in the neo-Victorian direction.)

Insofar as this anti-government frame is what Gerstle has in mind, we are seeing the return of the stronger state. We cannot go back to the New Deal because of those changes I outlined. Market decentralisation will have to be largely retained. You are welcome to nostalgia towards the pre-1984 regime, but don’t let it block hardheaded analysis.

The most obvious example of the need for a greater role for the state is the response to climate change. It is not an accident that there were neoliberals among the strongest deniers. While the market may be a part of the solution, as the New Zealand experience shows it is one in which there is a high level of government regulation. One of the reasons the world is failing to achieve its goals is there is there not a world government.

Another example is that there was once the belief that macroeconomic policy only involved the central bank regulating the stock of money (the monetarist approach). Practically, the belief quickly broke down; today central banks set interest rates, a far more Keynesian prescription. But only in the last decade or so, there has been a real acceptance that in many circumstances fiscal policy – the government’s responsibility – has to play a coordinating role.

I could give many other illustrations of where the government is being sucked into being more involved with the economy, but in the remaining space I want to list some of the major constraints upon government involvement.

First, both the government and the public are heavily in debt, which puts them in thrall to the finance sector terrorised by bond markets, as I described last week.

Second, there is a reluctance to acknowledge that great government intervention requires a change in the public-to-private spending balance and hence higher taxation. Those that have headlocked us into this position range from the Taxpayers’ Union through to the National Party and even the Prime Minister herself.

Third, while the rate of globalisation may be slowing down, and perhaps even retreating in some areas, especially for the trading of goods (not services), all countries remain locked into international trade. The deleterious impact of Brexit on the British economic performance well illustrates the consequence of denying this truism.

Fourth – I am not so clear about this – is that the US is finding it increasingly difficult to respond to new circumstances. Political management of the most powerful economy in the world may be seizing up. Given the ease with which we uncritically adopted the neoliberalism of the US and Britain (whose politics may also be seizing up), New Zealand may well find this as another headlock on our thinking.

Fifth, if we really are in secular stagnation, or even just a lower growth phase that the period of neoliberalism experienced, then a number of mechanisms which resolved the inherent conflicts no longer work.

Each of these constraints is a column – nay a book – in itself. They limit our ability to adapt to the new circumstances. But adapt we will. Gerstle’s book describes to the nuanced reader how political orders evolve internally, even if they pretend otherwise. But it provides no guarantee that the evolution will lead to a better world.